class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide # 1.5: Monopoly I: Behavior ## ECON 326 · Industrial Organization · Spring 2020 ### Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/IOs20
IOs20.classes.ryansafner.com
--- # Market Power I .left-column[ .center[ ![:scale 80%](https://www.dropbox.com/s/w5ecx0628ihm9n2/smith.png?raw=1) .smallest[ Adam Smith 1723-1790 ] ] ] .right-column[ > *"People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices,* (Book I, Chapter 2.2)" ] .source[Smith, Adam, 1776, [*An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations*](https://www.econlib.org/library/Smith/smWN.html)] --- # Market Power .pull-left[ - All sellers would like to raise prices and extract more revenue from consumers - .hi-purple[Competition] from *other* sellers drives prices down to match `\(MC(q)\)` (and bids costs and rents upwards to match prices) - If a firm in a competitive market raised `\(p>MC(q)\)`, would lose *all* of its customers - .hi[Market power]: ability to raise `\(p>MC(q)\)` and *not* lose *all* customers ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/3h37ge5bmvety7y/marketpower.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Monopoly .pull-left[ - We start with a simple model of .hi[monopoly]: a market with a *single* seller 1. Firm's products may have few close substitutes 2. .hi[Barriers to entry], making entry costly 3. Firm is a .hi-purple["price-searcher"]: can set optimal price `\(p^*\)` and quantity `\(q^*\)` - Must **search** for `\((q^*,p^*)\)` that maximizes `\(\pi\)` ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/6t0gb5f38aoe7pn/monopolyman.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Monopolist's Choice .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-1-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - Monopolist is constrained by relationship between quantity and price that consumers are willing to pay - .blue[Market (inverse) demand] describes maximum price consumers are willing to pay for a given quantity - Implications: - Monopolies can't set a price "as high as it wants" - Monopolies can still earn losses! ] --- # The Monopolist's Choice II .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-2-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - As monopolist chooses to produce more `\(q^*\)`, must lower the price on *all* units to sell them ] --- # The Monopolist's Choice II .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - As monopolist chooses to produce more `\(q^*\)`, must lower the price on *all* units to sell them - .red[Price effect]: lost revenue from lowering price on all sales ] --- # The Monopolist's Choice II .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - As monopolist chooses to produce more `\(q^*\)`, must lower the price on *all* units to sell them - .red[Price effect]: lost revenue from lowering price on all sales - .green[Output effect]: gained revenue from increase in sales ] --- # Monopoly and Revenues I - If a monopolist increases output, `\(\Delta q^*\)`, revenues would change by: .center[ `\(R(q)=\)`.green[`\\(p \Delta q\\)`] `\(+\)` .red[`\\(q \Delta p\\)`] ] -- - .green[Output effect]: increases number of units sold `\((\Delta q)\)` times price `\(p\)` per unit -- - .red[Price effect]: lowers price per unit `\((\Delta p)\)` on *all* units sold `\((q)\)` -- - Divide both sides by `\(\Delta q\)` to get .hi-purple[Marginal Revenue, `\\(MR(q)\\)`]: `$$\frac{\Delta R(q)}{\Delta q}=MR(q)=p+\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}q$$` -- .small[ - Compare: demand for a **competitive** firm is perfectly elastic: `\(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta}q=0\)`, so we saw `\(MR(q)=p\)`! ] --- # Monopoly and Revenues II - If we have a linear inverse demand function of the form `$$p=a+bq$$` - `\(a\)` is the choke price (intercept) - `\(b\)` is the slope -- - Marginal revenue again is defined as: `$$MR(q)=p+\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}q$$` -- - Recognize that `\(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\)` is the slope, `\(b\)`, `\(\left(\frac{rise}{run} \right)\)` --- # Monopoly and Revenues II `$$\begin{align*} MR(q)&=p+(b)q\\ MR(q)&=(a+bq)+bq\\ \mathbf{MR(q)}&=\mathbf{a+2bq}\\ \end{align*}$$` --- # Monopoly and Revenues III .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-5-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ `$$\begin{align*} p(q)&=a-bq\\ MR(q)&=a-2bq\\ \end{align*}$$` - Marginal revenue starts at same intercept as Demand `\((a)\)` with twice the slope `\((2b)\)` ] --- # Monopoly and Revenues: Example .content-box-green[ .green[**Example**]: Suppose the market demand is given by: `$$q=12.5-0.25p$$` ] 1. Find the function for a monopolist's marginal revenue curve. 2. Calculate the monopolist's marginal revenue if the firm produces 6 units, and 7 units. --- # Revenues and Price Elasticity of Demand .pull-left[ | Price Elasticity | `\(MR(q)\)` | `\(R(q)\)` | |------------------|---------|--------| | `\(\vert \epsilon \vert >1\)` Elastic | `\(+\)` | Increasing | | `\(\vert \epsilon \vert =1\)` Unit | `\(0\)` | Maximized | | `\(\vert \epsilon \vert <1\)` Inelastic | `\(-\)` | Decreasing | - Strong relationship between .hi[price elasticity of demand] and monopoly pricing - Monopolists *only* produce where demand is elastic, with positive `\(MR(q)\)`! - Check back later in [today's class notes](/class/1.5-class) for more ] .pull-right[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-6-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-7-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Measuring Markup Prices .pull-left[ - Perfect competition: `\(p=MC(q)\)` (allocatively efficient) - Monopolists .hi-purple[mark up] price above `\(MC(q)\)` - How much does a monopolist mark up price over cost? ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/rh4v98afnjit8zc/markup.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # Measuring Markup Prices .pull-left[ - .hi-purple[Size of markup depends on **price elasticity of demand**] - `\(\downarrow\)` price elasticity: `\(\uparrow\)` markup - i.e. the *less* responsive to prices consumers are, the *higher* the monopolist can charge ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/rh4v98afnjit8zc/markup.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Lerner Index I .pull-left[ - .hi[Lerner Index] measures market power as % of firm's price that is markup above (marginal) cost `$$L=\frac{p-MC(q)}{p} = -\frac{1}{\epsilon}$$` - `\(L=0 \implies\)` perfect competition - (since `\(P=MC)\)` - As `\(L\rightarrow 1 \implies\)` more market power ] .pull-right[ .center[ ![](https://www.dropbox.com/s/rh4v98afnjit8zc/markup.jpg?raw=1) ] ] --- # The Lerner Index II .center[ .smallest[ The more (less) elastic a good, the less (more) the optimal markup: `\(L=\frac{p-MC(q)}{p}=-\frac{1}{\epsilon}\)` ] ] .pull-left[ .center[ .smallest[ "Inelastic" Demand Curve ] ] <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-8-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ .center[ .smallest[ "Elastic" Demand Curve ] ] <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-9-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Profit-Maximizing Price and Quantity (Graph) .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-10-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - Profit-maximizing quantity is always `\(q^*\)` where .purple[`\\(MR(q)\\)`] `\(=\)` .red[`\\(MC(q)\\)`] ] --- # Profit-Maximizing Price and Quantity (Graph) .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-11-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - Profit-maximizing quantity is always `\(q^*\)` where .purple[`\\(MR(q)\\)`] `\(=\)` .red[`\\(MC(q)\\)`] - But monopolist faces *entire* .blue[market demand] - Can charge as high as consumers are WTP ] --- # Profit-Maximizing Price and Quantity (Graph) .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-12-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - Profit-maximizing quantity is always `\(q^*\)` where .purple[`\\(MR(q)\\)`] `\(=\)` .red[`\\(MC(q)\\)`] - But monopolist faces *entire* .blue[market demand] - Can charge as high as consumers are WTP - .orange[Break even price] `\(p=AC(q)_{min}\)` ] --- # Profit-Maximizing Price and Quantity (Graph) .pull-left[ <img src="1.5-slides_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-13-1.png" width="504" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ - Profit-maximizing quantity is always `\(q^*\)` where .purple[`\\(MR(q)\\)`] `\(=\)` .red[`\\(MC(q)\\)`] - But monopolist faces *entire* .blue[market demand] - Can charge as high as consumers are WTP - .orange[Break even price] `\(p=AC(q)_{min}\)` - .brown[Shut-down price] `\(p=AVC(q)_{min}\)` ] --- # Monopolist's Supply Decisions 1. Produce the optimal amount of output `\(q^*\)` where `\(MR(q)=MC(q)\)` -- 2. **Raise price to maximum consumers are WTP: `\(p^*=Demand(q^*)\)`** -- 3. Calculate profit with average cost: `\(\pi=[p-AC(q)]q\)` -- 4. Shut down in the *short run* if `\(p<AVC(q)\)` - Minimum of AVC curve where `\(MC(q)=AVC(q)\)` -- 5. Exit in the *long run* if `\(p<AC(q)\)` - Minimum of AC curve where `\(MC(q)=AC(q)\)` --- # The Profit Maximizing Quantity & Price: Example .content-box-green[ .smaller[ .green[**Example**]: Consider the market for iPhones. Suppose Apple's costs are: `$$\begin{align*} C(q)&=2.5q^2+25,000\\ MC(q)&=5q\\ \end{align*}$$` The demand for iPhones is given by (quantity is in millions of iPhones): `$$q=300-0.2p$$` ] ] .smaller[ 1. Find Apple's profit-maximizing quantity and price. 2. How much total profit does Apple earn? 3. How much of Apple's price is markup over (marginal) cost? 4. What is the price elasticity of demand at Apple's profit-maximizing output? ]