Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Coase's fundamental insight [was] that transaction, coordination, and contracting costs must be considered explicitly in explaining the extent of vertical integration...[We] explore one particular cost of using the market system-the possibility of postcontractual opportunistic behavior," (p.297)
"The particular circumstance we emphasize as likely to produce a serious threat of this type of reneging on contracts is the presence of appropriable specialized quasi rents. After a specific investment is made and such quasi rents are created, the possibility of opportunistic behavior is very real. Following Coase's framework, this problem can be solved in two possible ways: vertical integration or contracts," (p.298)
Recap: contracting removes parties from a competitive market and creates bilateral dependency between them
Two general solutions:
Contract: an agreement through which exchange is mediated
Anglo-American common law recognizes a contract to be valid if there is:
Valid contracts create legal rights and duties that are enforceable by courts
An aggreived party can sue the other party for breach of contract, and court will enforce sanctions
Courts may cancel contracts or require the party in breach to pay damages
In economics & contract theory, a complete contract specifies all actions or transfers that parties must take under every possible contingency
In the real world of uncertainty, complete contracts are impossible
Instead people maximize their expected utility given limited information at the time ("bounded rationality")
Agreements are always incomplete contracts, actions for many (unforeseen) contingencies are unspecified
Even for specified actions and contingences, outcomes are indeterminate due to enforcement costs
Gives rise to opportunism (shirking, fraud, renegotiation, hold-up, etc)
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"The primary alternative to vertical integration as a solution to the general problem of opportunistic behavior is some form of economically enforceable long-term contract," (p. 302).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Long-term contracts used as alternatives to vertical integration can be assumed to take two forms: (1) an explicitly stated contractual guarantee legally enforced by the government or some other outside institution, or (2) an implicit contractual guarantee enforced by the market mechanism of withdrawing future business if opportunistic behavior occurs...[However, they are] often very costly solutions. They entail costs of specifying possible contingencies and the policing and litigation costs of detecting violations and enforcing the contract in the courts," (p.303)
Vertical integration creates its own administrative and agency costs
Alternative contract solutions exist, often called "vertical restraints", e.g.:
Franchise contract: a franchisor leases use of its key nontangible assets to franchisee
Franchisor's non-tangible assets leased: business model, use of brand name, logos, trademarks, trade secrets, know-how, etc.
Franchisee as entrepreneur owns/rents and manages physical assets (retail location, capital equipment, etc) & bears the risk
Franchisee pays franchisor fees & royalties to license franchisor's brand
Economies of scale with national ("corporate") advertising, business strategy, name-recognition for all franchisees licensing the same brand
Franchise contract contains many restraints on what franchisee may do with franchisor's brand, why?
Franchisor has incentive to find efficient way to monitor itself and franchisees to maintain quality
Common stipulations in franchising agreements:
Many contracts (including franchises) have exclusive dealing or tie-in agreements that require firm (e.g. franchisee) to purchase inputs exclusively from other firm (e.g. franchisor) or designated third-party
Sound like monopoly power?
Efficient response to horizontal & vertical free riding problem
Franchisors often include territorial restraints to create exlusive territories for franchisees
Removes competition between franchisees in geographic area
Avoids cannabalizing one another and diluting the franchisor's brand
A manufacturer in long-term contracts with retailers will often require resale or retail price maintenance (RPM):
Sound like a cartel agreement?
Or maybe manufacturer trying to prevent retailers from horizontal free riding on maintaining the manufacturer's brand
Lester G Telser
1931-
"If some retailers [provide extra] services [such as advertising, pre-sale demonstrations, etc] and ask for a corespondingly higher price whereas others do not provide the services and offer to sell the product to consumersat a lower price then an unstable situation emerges. Sales are diverted from the retailers who do provide the special services at the higher price to the retailers who do not provide the special services and offer to sell the product at the lower price....A customer,because of the special services provide by one retailer, is persuaded to buy the product. But he purchases the product from another paying the latter a lower price. In this way the retailers who do not provide the special services get a free ride at the expense of those who have convinced consumers to buy the product," (pp. 91-92).
Lester G Telser
1931-
"[The manufacturer can prevent] this by establishing a minimum retail price that guarantees a minimum gross markup. Therefore retailers are forced to compete by providing special services with the product and not by reducing the retail price," (pp. 91-92).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"When specific human capital is involved, the opportunism problem is often more complex and, because of laws prohibiting slavery, the solution is generally some form of explicit or implicit contract rather than vertical integration," (p.315)
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
When the specific asset is human capital, firms generally resort to long-term contracts, not vertical integration
Firms cannot own their labor inputs!
Compulsory arbitration clauses
Bonds that employers or employees forfeit (a "hostage") for bad behavior, or leaving the company too soon
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Contractual provisions specifying compulsory arbitration or more directly imposing costs on the opportunistic party (for example, via bonding) are alternatives often employed to economize on litigation costs and to create flexibility without specifying every possible contingency and quality dimension of the transaction," (p.303)
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Since every contingency cannot be cheaply specified in a contract or even known and because legal redress is expensive, transactors will generally also rely on an implicit type of long-term contract that employs a market rather than legal enforcement mechanism, namely, the imposition of a capital loss by the withdrawal of expected future business. This goodwill market-enforcement mechanism undoubtedly is a major element of the contractual alternative to vertical integration," (p.303)
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"One way in which this market mechanism of contract enforcement may operate is by offering to the potential cheater a future 'premium,' more precisely, a price sufficiently greater than average variable (that is, avoidable) cost to assure a quasi-rent stream that will exceed the potential gain from cheating. The present-discounted value of this future premium stream must be greater than any increase in wealth that could be obtained by the potential cheater if he, in fact, cheated and were terminated. The offer of such a long-term relationship with the potential cheater will eliminate systematic opportunistic behavior," (p.304).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"The larger the potential one-time 'theft' by cheating (the longer and more costly to detect a violation, enforce the contract, switch suppliers, and so forth) and the shorter the expected continuing business relationship, the higher this premium will be in a nondeceiving equilibrium. This may therefore partially explain both the reliance by firms on long-term implicit contracts with particular suppliers and the existence of reciprocity agreements among firms...The threat of termination of this relationship mutually suppresses opportunistic behavior. The premium stream can be usefully thought of as insurance payments made by the firm to prevent cheating," (pp.304-5)
Essentially playing1 an infinitely repeated Prisoners' Dilemma2
Game theory of repeated games
1 Where Buyer can be a consumer or another firm
2 "Infinitely" = game does not have a clear final turn.
Each player will always Cooperate iff: ∞-payoff stream of (C,C)>payoff of 1 (D,C)+∞-payoff stream of (D,D)
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Any profits are competed away in equilibrium by competitive expenditures on fixed (sunk) assets, such as initial specific investments (for example, a sign) with low or zero salvage value if the firm cheats, necessary to enter and obtain this preferred position of collecting the premium stream. These fixed (sunk) costs of supplying credibility of future performance are repaid or covered by future sales on which a premium is earned. In equilibrium,the premium stream is then merely a normal rate of return on the 'reputation,' or 'brand-name' capital created by the firm by these initial expenditures. This brand-name capital, the value of which is highly specific to contract fulfillment by the firm, is analytically equivalent to a forfeitable collateral bond put up by the firm which is anticipated to face an opportunity to take advantage of appropriable quasi rents in specialized assets," (p.306).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Benjamin Klein
1943-
We can generally say that the larger the appropriable specialized quasi rents (and therefore the larger the potential short-run gain from opportunistic behavior) and the larger the premium payments necessary to prevent contractual reneging, the more costly this implicit contractual solution will be...the lower the appropriable specialized quasi rents, the more likely that transactors will rely on a contractual relationship rather than common ownership. And conversely, integration by common or joint ownership is more likely, the higher the appropriable specialized quasi rents of the assets involved," (pp.306-307).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"Klein et al. (1978) and Williamson (1979) added further content by arguing that a contractual relationship between a separately owned buyer and seller will be plagued by opportunistic and inefficient behavior in situations in which there are large amounts of surplus to be divided ex post and in which, because of the impossibility of writing a complete, contingent contract, the ex ante contract does not specify a clear division of this surplus. Such situations in turn are likely to arise when either the buyer or seller must make investments that have a smaller value in a use outside their own relationship than within the relationship (i.e., there exist 'asset specificities')," (p.692).
Hart, Oliver and Sanford J Grossman, 1986, "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-719
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"While these statements help us understand when the costs of contracting between separately owned firms may be high, they do not elucidate what the benefits are of 'organizing the transaction within the firm.' In particular, given that it is difficult to write a complete contract between a buyer and seller and this creates room for opportunistic behavior, the transactions cost-based arguments for integration do not explain how the scope for such behavior changes when one of the self-interested owners becomes an equally self-interested employee of the other owner," (p.692).
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"A second question raised by the transactions cost-based arguments concerns the definition of integration itself. In particular, what does it mean for one firm to be more integrated than another? For example, is a firm that calls its retail force 'employees' more integrated than one that calls its retail force 'independent but exclusive sales agents'?"
"Existing theories cannot answer these questions because they do not give a sufficiently clear definition of integration for its costs and benefits to be assessed...We define integration in terms of the ownership of assets and develop a model to explain when one firm will desire to acquire the assets of another firm," (p.693).
Hart, Oliver and Sanford J Grossman, 1986, "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-719
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
"[I]f I am quite sure what kinds of actions my neighbour contemplates, I might be indifferent between his owning the field at the bottom of my garden and my owning it but renting it out for him to graze his horse in. But once I take into account that he may discover some new use for the field that I haven't yet thought of, but would find objectionable, it will be in my interest to own the field so as to put the use of it under my own control. More generally, ownership of a resource reduces exposure to unexpected events. Property rights are a means of reducing uncertainty without needing to know precisely what the source or nature of the future concern will be," (Littlechild 1986, p. 35.)
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"We define the firm as being composed of the assets (e.g., machines, inventories) that it owns. We present a theory of costly contracts that emphasizes that contractual rights can be of two types: specific rights and residual rights. When it is too costly for one party to specify a long list of the particular rights it desires over another party's assets, it may be optimal for that party to purchase all the rights except those specifically mentioned in the contract. Ownership is the purchase of these residual rights of control." (p.692).
Hart, Oliver and Sanford J Grossman, 1986, "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-719
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"We show that there can be harmful effects associated with the wrong allocation of residual rights. In particular, a firm that purchases its supplier, thereby removing residual rights of control from the manager of the supplying company, can distort the manager's incentives sufficiently to make common ownership harmful. We develop a theory of integration based on the attempt of parties in writing a contract to allocate efficiently the residual rights of control between themselves." (p.692).
Hart, Oliver and Sanford J Grossman, 1986, "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-719
Oliver Hart
1948-
Economics Nobel 2016
"[W]hen it is too costly for one party to specify a long list of the particular rights it desires over another party's assets, then it may be optimal for the first party to purchase all rights except those specifically mentioned in the contract. Ownership is the purchase of these residual rights of control. Vertical integration is the purchase of the assets of a supplier (or of a purchaser) for the purpose of acquiring the residual rights of control." (p.716).
Hart, Oliver and Sanford J Grossman, 1986, "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration," Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691-719
Any contract can specific who has control rights under specific circumstances
Designate a party that has residual control rights to determine what is to be done in an unspecified circumstance
Vertical integration = purchasing firm buys right to determine non-specified decisions of purchased firm
Purchased firm (supplier) becomes a division of the purchasing firm
Costs of common ownership/vertical integration:
Manager of division (formerly independent firm) no longer has residual control rights
Thus, it's very important to allocate ownership correctly!
If know the Coase Theorem: same idea!
Benjamin Klein
1943-
"Coase's fundamental insight [was] that transaction, coordination, and contracting costs must be considered explicitly in explaining the extent of vertical integration...[We] explore one particular cost of using the market system-the possibility of postcontractual opportunistic behavior," (p.297)
"The particular circumstance we emphasize as likely to produce a serious threat of this type of reneging on contracts is the presence of appropriable specialized quasi rents. After a specific investment is made and such quasi rents are created, the possibility of opportunistic behavior is very real. Following Coase's framework, this problem can be solved in two possible ways: vertical integration or contracts," (p.298)
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |