+ - 0:00:00
Notes for current slide
Notes for next slide

1.7: Monopoly III: Pricing

ECON 326 · Industrial Organization · Spring 2020

Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/IOs20
IOs20.classes.ryansafner.com

Profit-Seeking Firms

  • Any firm with market power seeks to maximize profits

  • Wants to (1st) create a surplus

Profit-Seeking Firms

  • Any firm with market power seeks to maximize profits

  • Wants to (1st) create a surplus and then extract some of it as profit

    • i.e. convert CS into \(\pi\)
  • Consumers are still better off than without the firm because it creates value (consumer surplus)

    • Just not as best-off as under perfect competition

Most Firms Create More Value than They Can Capture!

William Nordhaus

(1941-)

Economics Nobel 2018

"We conclude that [about 2.2%] of the social returns from technological advances over the 1948-2001 period was captured by producers, indicating that most of the benefits of technological change are passed on to consumers rather than captured by producers," (p.1)

Nordhaus, William, 2004, "Schumpeterian Profits in the American Economy: Theory and Measurement," NBER Working Paper 10433

Price Discrimination

  • The most obvious way to capture more surplus is to raise prices

    • But Law of Demand \(\implies\) this would turn many customers away!
  • Instead, if firm could charge different customers with different WTP different prices, firm could convert more consumer surplus into profit

  • "Price discrimination" or "Variable pricing"

The Economics of Pricing Strategy I

  • Two conditions are required for a firm to engage in variable pricing:

1: Firm must have market power

  • A competitive firm must charge the market price

The Economics of Pricing Strategy II

  • Two conditions are required for a firm to engage in variable pricing:

1: Firm must have market power

  • A competitive firm must charge the market price

2: Firms must be able to prevent resale or arbitrage

  • Smart customers buy in your lower-price market and resell it to your higher-price market

The Economics of Pricing Strategy II

  • Firm must acquire information about the variations in its customers' demands

  • Can the firm identify consumers' demands before they buy the product?

The Economics of Pricing Strategy II

  • With perfect information \(\implies\) Perfect or 1st-degree price discrimination

  • Charge a different price to each customer (their max WTP)

The Economics of Pricing Strategy II

  • With imperfect information \(\implies\) 3rd-degree price discrimination

  • Separate customers into groups (by demand differences) and charge each group a different price

The Economics of Pricing Strategy III

  • 2nd-degree price discrimination: More indirect forms of pricing: tying, bundling, quantity-discounts
    • Firm does not have enough information to categorize customers into groups
    • Consumers self-select into their own group

1st-Degree Price Discrimination

1st-Degree Price Discrimination I

  • If firm has perfect information about every customer's demand before purchase:

  • Perfect or 1st-degree price discrimination: firm charges each customer their maximum willingness to pay

    • "walks" down the market demand curve customer by customer

1st-Degree Price Discrimination II

  • Firm converts all consumer surplus into profit!

  • Produces the competitive amount (8)

1st-Degree Price Discrimination: Example

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination I

  • Firms almost never have perfect information about their customers

  • But they can often separate customers by observable characteristics into different groups that have similar demands before purchasing

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination I

  • Firms segment the market or engage in 3rd-degree price discrimination by charging different prices to different groups of customers

  • By far the most common type of price-discrimination

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination II

Business Travelers (Less Elastic)

Vacationers (More Elastic)

  • Consider airlines: different groups of travelers have different demands & price elasticities

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination II

Business Travelers (Less Elastic)

Vacationers (More Elastic)

  • The firm could charge a single price to all travelers and earn some profit

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination II

Business Travelers (Less Elastic)

Vacationers (More Elastic)

  • With different prices: raise price on inelastic travelers, lower price on elastic travelers, earn more profit!

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples I

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples I

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples II

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples III

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples IV

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Examples IV

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: Numerical Example

Example: Suppose you run a bar in downtown Frederick, and estimate the demands for beer from undergraduates \((U)\) and graduates \((G)\) to be:

$$\begin{align*} q_U&=18-4p_U\\ q_G&=12-p_G\\ \end{align*}$$

Assume the only cost of producing drinks is a constant marginal (and average) cost of $2.

  1. If your bar could not price discriminate, how much profit would the bar earn?

  2. If you could price discriminate, how much profit would the bar earn?

3rd-Degree Price Discrimination: You Try

Example: Promoters of a major college basketball tournament estimate that the demand for tickets for adults \((A)\) and students \((S)\) are given by:

$$\begin{align*} q_A&=5,000-10p_A\\ q_S&=10,000-100p_S\\ \end{align*}$$

Assume a constant marginal (and average) cost of $10/seat.

  1. If the organizers charged a single price, how much profit would the tournament earn?

  2. If the organizers segment the market and charge adults and students different prices, how much profit would the tournament earn?

Pricing

  • How much should each segment be charged?

  • Firm treats each segment as a different market (set \(MR(q)=MC(q)\) and then raise price to max WTP)

  • Lerner index implies optimal markup for each segment, again: $$\underbrace{\frac{p-MC(q)}{p}}_{Markup}=-\frac{1}{\epsilon}$$

Ways to Segment Markets

  • By customer characteristics

    • Age
    • Gender
  • Past purchase behavior

    • repeat customers (more price sensitive)
  • By location

    • local demand characteristics

2nd-Degree Price Discrimination

2nd-Degree Price Discrimination I

  • If firm cannot identify customers' demands or types before purchase

  • Indirect or 2nd-degree price discrimination: firm offers difference price-quantity bundles and allows customers self-select their offer

  • Ex: quantity-discounts or block pricing

    • Larger quantities offered at lower prices

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad?

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad? I

  • Ideal competitive market, \(q^*\) where \(p^c=MC\)

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad? I

  • Ideal competitive market, \(q^c\) where \(p^c=MC\)

  • A pure monopolist would produce less \(q^m\) at higher \(p^m\)

    • reduce consumer surplus and create deadweight loss
  • Transfer of some surplus from consumers to producers

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad? I

  • A price-discriminating monopolist transfers MORE surplus from consumers to producers

  • But encourages monopolist to produce more than the pure monopoly level and reduce deadweight loss!

    • At best, also produces at competitive output level!

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad? II

  • Price-discrimination creates incentives for innovation and risk-taking

  • Firms with high fixed costs of investment earn great profits, can recover their fixed costs

  • Might not do so without ability to price-discriminate

Is Price Discrimination Good or Bad? III

  • As with markups in general, price discrimination has everything to do with price elasticity of demand

  • If you are paying too much and losing consumer surplus, the real "problem" is that your demand is very inelastic

    • fewer options, a particular brand, or a necessity, limited time, etc
  • If you want to pay less, buy generic (more elastic)

Tying I

  • Firms often tie multiple goods together, where you must buy both goods in order to consume the product

    • One good often the "base" and the other are "refills" that you may need to buy more of
  • This is actually a method of intertemporal price-discrimination!

"scale 80%

Tying II

  • Companies often sell printers at marginal cost (no markup) and sell the ink/refills at a much higher markup

  • Reduce arbitrage:

    • printer requires specific ink
    • ink only words with that specific printer

Tying II

  • Segment the market into:
  1. High-volume users: buy more ink over time; pay more per sheet printed

  2. Low-volume users: buy less ink; pay less per sheet printed

  • Indirect price-discrimination: firms don't know what kind of user you are in advance

Tying: Good or Bad?

  • Again, a tradeoff between benefits and costs:

  • Increased profits and reduced consumer surplus, reduced deadweight loss

  • Spreads fixed cost of research & development over more users

Tying: Good or Bad?

  • If printers & ink were not tied:

    • printers would be more expensive
    • ink would be cheaper
  • High-volume users would keep buying ink and save money (vs. tied)

  • Low-volume users might not buy the (now expensive) printer at all!

Bundling I

  • Firms often bundle products together as a single package, and refuse to offer individual parts of the package

  • Often, consumers do not want all products in the bundle

  • Or, if they were able to buy just part of the bundle, they would not buy the other parts

Bundling II

Example: Consider two consumers, each have different reservation prices to buy components in Microsoft Office bundle

Amy's WTP Ben's WTP
MS Word $70 $40
MS Excel $50 $60
  • Microsoft could charge separate prices for MS Word and MS Excel

Bundling II

Example: Consider two consumers, each have different reservation prices to buy components in Microsoft Office bundle

Amy's WTP Ben's WTP
MS Word $70 $40
MS Excel $50 $60
  • Microsoft could charge separate prices for MS Word and MS Excel

  • MS Word: both would buy at $40, generating $80 of revenues

Bundling II

Example: Consider two consumers, each have different reservation prices to buy components in Microsoft Office bundle

Amy's WTP Ben's WTP
MS Word $70 $40
MS Excel $50 $60
  • Microsoft could charge separate prices for MS Word and MS Excel

  • MS Word: both would buy at $40, generating $80 of revenues

  • MS Excel: both would buy at $50, generating $100 of revenues

Bundling II

Example: Consider two consumers, each have different reservation prices to buy components in Microsoft Office bundle

Amy's WTP Ben's WTP
MS Word $70 $40
MS Excel $50 $60
  • Microsoft could charge separate prices for MS Word and MS Excel

  • MS Word: both would buy at $40, generating $80 of revenues

  • MS Excel: both would buy at $50, generating $100 of revenues

  • Total revenues of individual sales: $180

Bundling II

Example: Consider two consumers, each have different reservation prices to buy components in Microsoft Office bundle

Amy's WTP Ben's WTP
MS Word $70 $40
MS Excel $50 $60
Bundle $120 $100
  • Microsoft could charge separate prices for MS Word and MS Excel

  • MS Word: both would buy at $40, generating $80 of revenues

  • MS Excel: both would buy at $50, generating $100 of revenues

  • Total revenues of individual sales: $180

  • Microsoft can instead add their individual reservation prices and bundle products together to force both consumers to buy both products

  • Bundle: both would buy at $100, generating $200 revenue

Bundling: Good or Bad?

  • Again, a tradeoff between benefits and costs:

  • Increased profits and reduced consumer surplus, reduced deadweight loss

  • Spreads fixed cost of research & development over more users

  • Goods with high fixed costs and low marginal costs (software, TV, music) increase profits from bundling

    • increases innovation and investment in these industries

Paused

Help

Keyboard shortcuts

, , Pg Up, k Go to previous slide
, , Pg Dn, Space, j Go to next slide
Home Go to first slide
End Go to last slide
Number + Return Go to specific slide
b / m / f Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode
c Clone slideshow
p Toggle presenter mode
t Restart the presentation timer
?, h Toggle this help
Esc Back to slideshow